StudentsEducators

Keynesian Cross

The Keynesian Cross is a graphical representation used in Keynesian economics to illustrate the relationship between aggregate demand and total output (or income) in an economy. It demonstrates how the equilibrium level of output is determined where planned expenditure equals actual output. The model consists of a 45-degree line that represents points where aggregate demand equals total output. When the aggregate demand curve is above the 45-degree line, it indicates that planned spending exceeds actual output, leading to increased production and employment. Conversely, if the aggregate demand is below the 45-degree line, it signals that output exceeds spending, resulting in unplanned inventory accumulation and decreasing production. This framework highlights the importance of government intervention in boosting demand during economic downturns, thereby stabilizing the economy.

Other related terms

contact us

Let's get started

Start your personalized study experience with acemate today. Sign up for free and find summaries and mock exams for your university.

logoTurn your courses into an interactive learning experience.
Antong Yin

Antong Yin

Co-Founder & CEO

Jan Tiegges

Jan Tiegges

Co-Founder & CTO

Paul Herman

Paul Herman

Co-Founder & CPO

© 2025 acemate UG (haftungsbeschränkt)  |   Terms and Conditions  |   Privacy Policy  |   Imprint  |   Careers   |  
iconlogo
Log in

Harrod-Domar Model

The Harrod-Domar Model is an economic theory that explains how investment can lead to economic growth. It posits that the level of investment in an economy is directly proportional to the growth rate of the economy. The model emphasizes two main variables: the savings rate (s) and the capital-output ratio (v). The basic formula can be expressed as:

G=svG = \frac{s}{v}G=vs​

where GGG is the growth rate of the economy, sss is the savings rate, and vvv is the capital-output ratio. In simpler terms, the model suggests that higher savings can lead to increased investments, which in turn can spur economic growth. However, it also highlights potential limitations, such as the assumption of a stable capital-output ratio and the disregard for other factors that can influence growth, like technological advancements or labor force changes.

Topology Optimization

Topology Optimization is an advanced computational design technique used to determine the optimal material layout within a given design space, subject to specific constraints and loading conditions. This method aims to maximize performance while minimizing material usage, leading to lightweight and efficient structures. The process involves the use of mathematical formulations and numerical algorithms to iteratively adjust the distribution of material based on stress, strain, and displacement criteria.

Typically, the optimization problem can be mathematically represented as:

Minimize f(x)subject to gi(x)≤0,hj(x)=0\text{Minimize } f(x) \quad \text{subject to } g_i(x) \leq 0, \quad h_j(x) = 0Minimize f(x)subject to gi​(x)≤0,hj​(x)=0

where f(x)f(x)f(x) represents the objective function, gi(x)g_i(x)gi​(x) are inequality constraints, and hj(x)h_j(x)hj​(x) are equality constraints. The results of topology optimization can lead to innovative geometries that would be difficult to conceive through traditional design methods, making it invaluable in fields such as aerospace, automotive, and civil engineering.

Avl Trees

AVL Trees, named after their inventors Adelson-Velsky and Landis, are a type of self-balancing binary search tree. In an AVL tree, the heights of the two child subtrees of any node differ by at most one, ensuring that the tree remains balanced. This balance is maintained through rotations during insertions and deletions, which allows for efficient search, insertion, and deletion operations with a time complexity of O(log⁡n)O(\log n)O(logn). The balancing condition can be expressed using the balance factor, defined for any node as the height of the left subtree minus the height of the right subtree. If the balance factor of any node becomes less than -1 or greater than 1, rebalancing through rotations is necessary to restore the AVL property. This makes AVL trees particularly suitable for applications that require frequent insertions and deletions while maintaining quick access times.

Jacobian Matrix

The Jacobian matrix is a fundamental concept in multivariable calculus and differential equations, representing the first-order partial derivatives of a vector-valued function. Given a function F:Rn→Rm\mathbf{F}: \mathbb{R}^n \to \mathbb{R}^mF:Rn→Rm, the Jacobian matrix JJJ is defined as:

J=[∂F1∂x1∂F1∂x2⋯∂F1∂xn∂F2∂x1∂F2∂x2⋯∂F2∂xn⋮⋮⋱⋮∂Fm∂x1∂Fm∂x2⋯∂Fm∂xn]J = \begin{bmatrix} \frac{\partial F_1}{\partial x_1} & \frac{\partial F_1}{\partial x_2} & \cdots & \frac{\partial F_1}{\partial x_n} \\ \frac{\partial F_2}{\partial x_1} & \frac{\partial F_2}{\partial x_2} & \cdots & \frac{\partial F_2}{\partial x_n} \\ \vdots & \vdots & \ddots & \vdots \\ \frac{\partial F_m}{\partial x_1} & \frac{\partial F_m}{\partial x_2} & \cdots & \frac{\partial F_m}{\partial x_n} \end{bmatrix}J=​∂x1​∂F1​​∂x1​∂F2​​⋮∂x1​∂Fm​​​∂x2​∂F1​​∂x2​∂F2​​⋮∂x2​∂Fm​​​⋯⋯⋱⋯​∂xn​∂F1​​∂xn​∂F2​​⋮∂xn​∂Fm​​​​

Here, each entry ∂Fi∂xj\frac{\partial F_i}{\partial x_j}∂xj​∂Fi​​ represents the rate of change of the iii-th function component with respect to the jjj-th variable. The

Stackelberg Equilibrium

The Stackelberg Equilibrium is a concept in game theory that describes a strategic interaction between firms in an oligopoly setting, where one firm (the leader) makes its production decision before the other firm (the follower). This sequential decision-making process allows the leader to optimize its output based on the expected reactions of the follower. In this equilibrium, the leader anticipates the follower's best response and chooses its output level accordingly, leading to a distinct outcome compared to simultaneous-move games.

Mathematically, if qLq_LqL​ represents the output of the leader and qFq_FqF​ represents the output of the follower, the follower's reaction function can be expressed as qF=R(qL)q_F = R(q_L)qF​=R(qL​), where RRR is the reaction function derived from the follower's profit maximization. The Stackelberg equilibrium occurs when the leader chooses qLq_LqL​ that maximizes its profit, taking into account the follower's reaction. This results in a unique equilibrium where both firms' outputs are determined, and typically, the leader enjoys a higher market share and profits compared to the follower.

Phillips Curve Expectations

The Phillips Curve Expectations refers to the relationship between inflation and unemployment, which is influenced by the expectations of both variables. Traditionally, the Phillips Curve suggested an inverse relationship: as unemployment decreases, inflation tends to increase, and vice versa. However, when expectations of inflation are taken into account, this relationship becomes more complex.

Incorporating expectations means that if people anticipate higher inflation in the future, they may adjust their behavior accordingly—such as demanding higher wages, which can lead to a self-fulfilling cycle of rising prices and wages. This adjustment can shift the Phillips Curve, resulting in a vertical curve in the long run, where no trade-off exists between inflation and unemployment, summarized in the concept of the Natural Rate of Unemployment. Mathematically, this can be represented as:

πt=πte−β(ut−un)\pi_t = \pi_{t}^e - \beta(u_t - u_n)πt​=πte​−β(ut​−un​)

where πt\pi_tπt​ is the actual inflation rate, πte\pi_{t}^eπte​ is the expected inflation rate, utu_tut​ is the unemployment rate, unu_nun​ is the natural rate of unemployment, and β\betaβ is a positive constant. This illustrates how expectations play a crucial role in shaping economic dynamics.