StudentsEducators

Stackelberg Equilibrium

The Stackelberg Equilibrium is a concept in game theory that describes a strategic interaction between firms in an oligopoly setting, where one firm (the leader) makes its production decision before the other firm (the follower). This sequential decision-making process allows the leader to optimize its output based on the expected reactions of the follower. In this equilibrium, the leader anticipates the follower's best response and chooses its output level accordingly, leading to a distinct outcome compared to simultaneous-move games.

Mathematically, if qLq_LqL​ represents the output of the leader and qFq_FqF​ represents the output of the follower, the follower's reaction function can be expressed as qF=R(qL)q_F = R(q_L)qF​=R(qL​), where RRR is the reaction function derived from the follower's profit maximization. The Stackelberg equilibrium occurs when the leader chooses qLq_LqL​ that maximizes its profit, taking into account the follower's reaction. This results in a unique equilibrium where both firms' outputs are determined, and typically, the leader enjoys a higher market share and profits compared to the follower.

Other related terms

contact us

Let's get started

Start your personalized study experience with acemate today. Sign up for free and find summaries and mock exams for your university.

logoTurn your courses into an interactive learning experience.
Antong Yin

Antong Yin

Co-Founder & CEO

Jan Tiegges

Jan Tiegges

Co-Founder & CTO

Paul Herman

Paul Herman

Co-Founder & CPO

© 2025 acemate UG (haftungsbeschränkt)  |   Terms and Conditions  |   Privacy Policy  |   Imprint  |   Careers   |  
iconlogo
Log in

Lagrange Multipliers

Lagrange Multipliers is a mathematical method used to find the local maxima and minima of a function subject to equality constraints. It operates on the principle that if you want to optimize a function f(x,y)f(x, y)f(x,y) while adhering to a constraint g(x,y)=0g(x, y) = 0g(x,y)=0, you can introduce a new variable, known as the Lagrange multiplier λ\lambdaλ. The method involves setting up the Lagrangian function:

L(x,y,λ)=f(x,y)+λg(x,y)\mathcal{L}(x, y, \lambda) = f(x, y) + \lambda g(x, y)L(x,y,λ)=f(x,y)+λg(x,y)

To find the extrema, you take the partial derivatives of L\mathcal{L}L with respect to xxx, yyy, and λ\lambdaλ, and set them equal to zero:

∂L∂x=0,∂L∂y=0,∂L∂λ=0\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial x} = 0, \quad \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial y} = 0, \quad \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda} = 0∂x∂L​=0,∂y∂L​=0,∂λ∂L​=0

This results in a system of equations that can be solved to determine the optimal values of xxx, yyy, and λ\lambdaλ. This method is especially useful in various fields such as economics, engineering, and physics, where constraints are a common factor in optimization problems.

Vgg16

VGG16 is a convolutional neural network architecture that was developed by the Visual Geometry Group at the University of Oxford. It gained prominence for its performance in the ImageNet Large Scale Visual Recognition Challenge (ILSVRC) in 2014. The architecture consists of 16 layers that have learnable weights, which include 13 convolutional layers and 3 fully connected layers. The model is known for its simplicity and depth, utilizing small 3×33 \times 33×3 convolutional filters stacked on top of each other, which allows it to capture complex features while keeping the number of parameters manageable.

Key features of VGG16 include:

  • Pooling layers: After several convolutional layers, max pooling layers are added to downsample the feature maps, reducing dimensionality and computational complexity.
  • Activation functions: The architecture employs the ReLU (Rectified Linear Unit) activation function, which helps in mitigating the vanishing gradient problem during training.

Overall, VGG16 has become a foundational model in deep learning, often serving as a backbone for transfer learning in various computer vision tasks.

Mott Insulator Transition

The Mott insulator transition is a phenomenon that occurs in strongly correlated electron systems, where an insulating state emerges due to electron-electron interactions, despite a band theory prediction of metallic behavior. In a typical metal, electrons can move freely, leading to conductivity; however, in a Mott insulator, the interactions between electrons become so strong that they localize, preventing conduction. This transition is characterized by a critical parameter, often the ratio of kinetic energy to potential energy, denoted as U/tU/tU/t, where UUU is the on-site Coulomb interaction energy and ttt is the hopping amplitude of electrons between lattice sites. As this ratio is varied (for example, by changing the electron density or temperature), the system can transition from insulating to metallic behavior, showcasing the delicate balance between interaction and kinetic energy. The Mott insulator transition has important implications in various fields, including high-temperature superconductivity and the understanding of quantum phase transitions.

Riemann Mapping

The Riemann Mapping Theorem is a fundamental result in complex analysis that asserts the existence of a conformal (angle-preserving) mapping between simply connected open subsets of the complex plane. Specifically, if DDD is a simply connected domain in C\mathbb{C}C that is not the entire plane, then there exists a biholomorphic (one-to-one and onto) mapping f:D→Df: D \to \mathbb{D}f:D→D, where D\mathbb{D}D is the open unit disk. This mapping allows us to study properties of complex functions in a more manageable setting, as the unit disk is a well-understood domain. The significance of the theorem lies in its implications for uniformization, enabling mathematicians to classify complicated surfaces and study their properties via simpler geometrical shapes. Importantly, the Riemann Mapping Theorem also highlights the deep relationship between geometry and complex analysis.

Harberger’S Triangle

Harberger's Triangle is a conceptual tool used in public finance and economics to illustrate the efficiency costs of taxation. It visually represents the trade-offs between equity and efficiency when a government imposes taxes. The triangle is formed on a graph where the base represents the level of economic activity and the height signifies the deadweight loss created by taxation.

This deadweight loss occurs because taxes distort market behavior, leading to a reduction in the quantity of goods and services traded. The area of the triangle can be calculated as 12×base×height\frac{1}{2} \times \text{base} \times \text{height}21​×base×height, demonstrating how the inefficiencies grow as tax rates increase. Understanding Harberger's Triangle helps policymakers evaluate the impacts of tax policies on economic efficiency and inform decisions that balance revenue generation with minimal market distortion.

Borel-Cantelli Lemma In Probability

The Borel-Cantelli Lemma is a fundamental result in probability theory that provides insights into the occurrence of events in a sequence of trials. It consists of two parts:

  1. First Borel-Cantelli Lemma: If A1,A2,A3,…A_1, A_2, A_3, \ldotsA1​,A2​,A3​,… are events in a probability space and the sum of their probabilities is finite, that is,
∑n=1∞P(An)<∞, \sum_{n=1}^{\infty} P(A_n) < \infty,n=1∑∞​P(An​)<∞,

then the probability that infinitely many of the events AnA_nAn​ occur is zero:

P(lim sup⁡n→∞An)=0. P(\limsup_{n \to \infty} A_n) = 0.P(n→∞limsup​An​)=0.
  1. Second Borel-Cantelli Lemma: Conversely, if the events AnA_nAn​ are independent and the sum of their probabilities diverges, meaning
∑n=1∞P(An)=∞, \sum_{n=1}^{\infty} P(A_n) = \infty,n=1∑∞​P(An​)=∞,

then the probability that infinitely many of the events AnA_nAn​ occur is one:

P(lim sup⁡n→∞An)=1. P(\limsup_{n \to \infty} A_n) = 1.P(n→∞limsup​An​)=1.

This lemma is crucial in understanding the behavior of sequences of random events and helps to establish the conditions under which certain