StudentsEducators

Mach-Zehnder Interferometer

The Mach-Zehnder Interferometer is an optical device used to measure phase changes in light waves. It consists of two beam splitters and two mirrors arranged in such a way that a light beam is split into two separate paths. These paths can undergo different phase shifts due to external factors such as changes in the medium or environmental conditions. After traveling through their respective paths, the beams are recombined at the second beam splitter, leading to an interference pattern that can be analyzed.

The interference pattern is a result of the superposition of the two light beams, which can be constructive or destructive depending on the phase difference Δϕ\Delta \phiΔϕ between them. The intensity of the combined light can be expressed as:

I=I0(1+cos⁡(Δϕ))I = I_0 \left( 1 + \cos(\Delta \phi) \right)I=I0​(1+cos(Δϕ))

where I0I_0I0​ is the maximum intensity. This device is widely used in various applications, including precision measurements in physics, telecommunications, and quantum mechanics.

Other related terms

contact us

Let's get started

Start your personalized study experience with acemate today. Sign up for free and find summaries and mock exams for your university.

logoTurn your courses into an interactive learning experience.
Antong Yin

Antong Yin

Co-Founder & CEO

Jan Tiegges

Jan Tiegges

Co-Founder & CTO

Paul Herman

Paul Herman

Co-Founder & CPO

© 2025 acemate UG (haftungsbeschränkt)  |   Terms and Conditions  |   Privacy Policy  |   Imprint  |   Careers   |  
iconlogo
Log in

Central Limit

The Central Limit Theorem (CLT) is a fundamental principle in statistics that states that the distribution of the sample means approaches a normal distribution, regardless of the shape of the population distribution, as the sample size becomes larger. Specifically, if you take a sufficiently large number of random samples from a population and calculate their means, these means will form a distribution that approximates a normal distribution with a mean equal to the mean of the population (μ\muμ) and a standard deviation equal to the population standard deviation (σ\sigmaσ) divided by the square root of the sample size (nnn), represented as σn\frac{\sigma}{\sqrt{n}}n​σ​.

This theorem is crucial because it allows statisticians to make inferences about population parameters even when the underlying population distribution is not normal. The CLT justifies the use of the normal distribution in various statistical methods, including hypothesis testing and confidence interval estimation, particularly when dealing with large samples. In practice, a sample size of 30 is often considered sufficient for the CLT to hold true, although smaller samples may also work if the population distribution is not heavily skewed.

Sunk Cost

Sunk cost refers to expenses that have already been incurred and cannot be recovered. This concept is crucial in decision-making, as it highlights the fallacy of allowing past costs to influence current choices. For instance, if a company has invested $100,000 in a project but realizes that it is no longer viable, the sunk cost should not affect the decision to continue funding the project. Instead, decisions should be based on future costs and potential benefits. Ignoring sunk costs can lead to better economic choices and a more rational approach to resource allocation. In mathematical terms, if SSS represents sunk costs, the decision to proceed should rely on the expected future value VVV rather than SSS.

Yield Curve

The yield curve is a graphical representation that shows the relationship between interest rates and the maturity dates of debt securities, typically government bonds. It illustrates how yields vary with different maturities, providing insights into investor expectations about future interest rates and economic conditions. A normal yield curve slopes upwards, indicating that longer-term bonds have higher yields than short-term ones, reflecting the risks associated with time. Conversely, an inverted yield curve occurs when short-term rates are higher than long-term rates, often signaling an impending economic recession. The shape of the yield curve can also be categorized as flat or humped, depending on the relative yields across different maturities, and is a crucial tool for investors and policymakers in assessing market sentiment and economic forecasts.

Pareto Optimal

Pareto Optimalität, benannt nach dem italienischen Ökonomen Vilfredo Pareto, beschreibt einen Zustand in einer Ressourcenverteilung, bei dem es nicht möglich ist, das Wohlbefinden einer Person zu verbessern, ohne das Wohlbefinden einer anderen Person zu verschlechtern. In einem Pareto-optimalen Zustand sind alle Ressourcen so verteilt, dass die Effizienz maximiert ist. Das bedeutet, dass jede Umverteilung von Ressourcen entweder niemandem zugutekommt oder mindestens einer Person schadet. Mathematisch kann ein Zustand als Pareto-optimal angesehen werden, wenn es keine Möglichkeit gibt, die Utility-Funktion Ui(x)U_i(x)Ui​(x) einer Person iii zu erhöhen, ohne die Utility-Funktion Uj(x)U_j(x)Uj​(x) einer anderen Person jjj zu verringern. Die Analyse von Pareto-Optimalität wird häufig in der Wirtschaftstheorie und der Spieltheorie verwendet, um die Effizienz von Märkten und Verhandlungen zu bewerten.

Schelling Model

The Schelling Model, developed by economist Thomas Schelling in the 1970s, is a foundational concept in understanding how individual preferences can lead to large-scale social phenomena, particularly in the context of segregation. The model illustrates that even a slight preference for neighbors of the same kind can result in significant segregation over time, despite individuals not necessarily wishing to be entirely separated from others.

In the simplest form of the model, individuals are represented on a grid, where each square can be occupied by a person of one type (e.g., color) or remain empty. Each person prefers to have a certain percentage of neighbors that are similar to them. If this preference is not met, individuals will move to a different location, leading to an evolving pattern of segregation. This model highlights the importance of self-organization in social systems and demonstrates how individual actions can unintentionally create collective outcomes, often counter to the initial intentions of the individuals involved.

The implications of the Schelling Model extend to various fields, including urban studies, economics, and sociology, emphasizing how personal choices can shape societal structures.

Fama-French Model

The Fama-French Model is an asset pricing model developed by Eugene Fama and Kenneth French that extends the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) by incorporating additional factors to better explain stock returns. While the CAPM considers only the market risk factor, the Fama-French model includes two additional factors: size and value. The model suggests that smaller companies (the size factor, SMB - Small Minus Big) and companies with high book-to-market ratios (the value factor, HML - High Minus Low) tend to outperform larger companies and those with low book-to-market ratios, respectively.

The expected return on a stock can be expressed as:

E(Ri)=Rf+βi(E(Rm)−Rf)+si⋅SMB+hi⋅HMLE(R_i) = R_f + \beta_i (E(R_m) - R_f) + s_i \cdot SMB + h_i \cdot HMLE(Ri​)=Rf​+βi​(E(Rm​)−Rf​)+si​⋅SMB+hi​⋅HML

where:

  • E(Ri)E(R_i)E(Ri​) is the expected return of the asset,
  • RfR_fRf​ is the risk-free rate,
  • βi\beta_iβi​ is the sensitivity of the asset to market risk,
  • E(Rm)−RfE(R_m) - R_fE(Rm​)−Rf​ is the market risk premium,
  • sis_isi​ measures the exposure to the size factor,
  • hih_ihi​ measures the exposure to the value factor.

By accounting for these additional factors, the Fama-French model provides a more comprehensive framework for understanding variations in stock