StudentsEducators

Hawking Temperature Derivation

The derivation of Hawking temperature stems from the principles of quantum mechanics applied to black holes. Stephen Hawking proposed that particle-antiparticle pairs are constantly being created in the vacuum of space. Near the event horizon of a black hole, one of these particles can fall into the black hole while the other escapes, leading to the phenomenon of Hawking radiation. This escaping particle appears as radiation emitted from the black hole, and its energy corresponds to a temperature, known as the Hawking temperature.

The temperature THT_HTH​ can be derived using the formula:

TH=ℏc38πGMkBT_H = \frac{\hbar c^3}{8 \pi G M k_B}TH​=8πGMkB​ℏc3​

where:

  • ℏ\hbarℏ is the reduced Planck constant,
  • ccc is the speed of light,
  • GGG is the gravitational constant,
  • MMM is the mass of the black hole, and
  • kBk_BkB​ is the Boltzmann constant.

This equation shows that the temperature of a black hole is inversely proportional to its mass, implying that smaller black holes emit more radiation and thus have a higher temperature than larger ones.

Other related terms

contact us

Let's get started

Start your personalized study experience with acemate today. Sign up for free and find summaries and mock exams for your university.

logoTurn your courses into an interactive learning experience.
Antong Yin

Antong Yin

Co-Founder & CEO

Jan Tiegges

Jan Tiegges

Co-Founder & CTO

Paul Herman

Paul Herman

Co-Founder & CPO

© 2025 acemate UG (haftungsbeschränkt)  |   Terms and Conditions  |   Privacy Policy  |   Imprint  |   Careers   |  
iconlogo
Log in

Metric Space Compactness

In mathematics, a subset KKK of a metric space (X,d)(X, d)(X,d) is called compact if every open cover of KKK has a finite subcover. An open cover is a collection of open sets whose union contains KKK. Compactness can be intuitively understood as a generalization of closed and bounded subsets in Euclidean space, as encapsulated by the Heine-Borel theorem, which states that a subset of Rn\mathbb{R}^nRn is compact if and only if it is closed and bounded.

Another important aspect of compactness in metric spaces is that every sequence in a compact space has a convergent subsequence, with the limit also residing within the space, a property known as sequential compactness. This characteristic makes compact spaces particularly valuable in analysis and topology, as they allow for the application of various theorems that depend on convergence and continuity.

Polymer Electrolyte Membranes

Polymer Electrolyte Membranes (PEMs) are crucial components in various electrochemical devices, particularly in fuel cells and electrolyzers. These membranes are made from specially designed polymers that conduct protons (H+H^+H+) while acting as insulators for electrons, which allows them to facilitate electrochemical reactions efficiently. The most common type of PEM is based on sulfonated tetrafluoroethylene copolymers, such as Nafion.

PEMs enable the conversion of chemical energy into electrical energy in fuel cells, where hydrogen and oxygen react to produce water and electricity. The membranes also play a significant role in maintaining the separation of reactants, thereby enhancing the overall efficiency and performance of the system. Key properties of PEMs include ionic conductivity, chemical stability, and mechanical strength, which are essential for long-term operation in aggressive environments.

Stackelberg Equilibrium

The Stackelberg Equilibrium is a concept in game theory that describes a strategic interaction between firms in an oligopoly setting, where one firm (the leader) makes its production decision before the other firm (the follower). This sequential decision-making process allows the leader to optimize its output based on the expected reactions of the follower. In this equilibrium, the leader anticipates the follower's best response and chooses its output level accordingly, leading to a distinct outcome compared to simultaneous-move games.

Mathematically, if qLq_LqL​ represents the output of the leader and qFq_FqF​ represents the output of the follower, the follower's reaction function can be expressed as qF=R(qL)q_F = R(q_L)qF​=R(qL​), where RRR is the reaction function derived from the follower's profit maximization. The Stackelberg equilibrium occurs when the leader chooses qLq_LqL​ that maximizes its profit, taking into account the follower's reaction. This results in a unique equilibrium where both firms' outputs are determined, and typically, the leader enjoys a higher market share and profits compared to the follower.

Weierstrass Function

The Weierstrass function is a classic example of a continuous function that is nowhere differentiable. It is defined as a series of sine functions, typically expressed in the form:

W(x)=∑n=0∞ancos⁡(bnπx)W(x) = \sum_{n=0}^{\infty} a^n \cos(b^n \pi x)W(x)=n=0∑∞​ancos(bnπx)

where 0<a<10 < a < 10<a<1 and bbb is a positive odd integer, satisfying ab>1+3π2ab > 1+\frac{3\pi}{2}ab>1+23π​. The function is continuous everywhere due to the uniform convergence of the series, but its derivative does not exist at any point, showcasing the concept of fractal-like behavior in mathematics. This makes the Weierstrass function a pivotal example in the study of real analysis, particularly in understanding the intricacies of continuity and differentiability. Its pathological nature has profound implications in various fields, including mathematical analysis, chaos theory, and the understanding of fractals.

Market Structure Analysis

Market Structure Analysis is a critical framework used to evaluate the characteristics of a market, including the number of firms, the nature of products, entry and exit barriers, and the level of competition. It typically categorizes markets into four main types: perfect competition, monopolistic competition, oligopoly, and monopoly. Each structure has distinct implications for pricing, output decisions, and overall market efficiency. For instance, in a monopolistic market, a single firm controls the entire supply, allowing it to set prices without competition, while in a perfect competition scenario, numerous firms offer identical products, driving prices down to the level of marginal cost. Understanding these structures helps businesses and policymakers make informed decisions regarding pricing strategies, market entry, and regulatory measures.

Hahn Decomposition Theorem

The Hahn Decomposition Theorem is a fundamental result in measure theory, particularly in the study of signed measures. It states that for any signed measure μ\muμ defined on a measurable space, there exists a decomposition of the space into two disjoint measurable sets PPP and NNN such that:

  1. μ(A)≥0\mu(A) \geq 0μ(A)≥0 for all measurable sets A⊆PA \subseteq PA⊆P (the positive set),
  2. μ(B)≤0\mu(B) \leq 0μ(B)≤0 for all measurable sets B⊆NB \subseteq NB⊆N (the negative set).

The sets PPP and NNN are constructed such that every measurable set can be expressed as the union of a set from PPP and a set from NNN, ensuring that the signed measure can be understood in terms of its positive and negative parts. This theorem is essential for the development of the Radon-Nikodym theorem and plays a crucial role in various applications, including probability theory and functional analysis.